Decision Notice
DECISION NOTICE
1.
ACTION
1.1.
For the reasons given in this Notice, the Authority has decided to:
(1)
impose on Corrado Abbattista a financial penalty of £100,000, pursuant to
section 123(1) of the Act, for engaging in market manipulation in
contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation; and
(2)
make an order, pursuant to section 56 of the Act, prohibiting Mr Abbattista
from performing any function in relation to any regulated activities carried
on by an authorised or exempt person, or exempt professional firm.
2.
SUMMARY OF REASONS
2.1.
Between 20 January and 15 May 2017 (the “Relevant Period”), Mr Abbattista, an
experienced trader and a portfolio manager, partner and Chief Investment Officer
at Fenician Capital Management LLP (“Fenician”), in the course of his role with
Fenician, placed large orders (by reference to the average order size in those
shares in the market at that time) for CFDs referenced to the shares of Marks and
Spencer Group Plc (“M&S”), Diageo Plc (“Diageo”), Ibstock Plc (“Ibstock”),
Thomas Cook Group Plc (“Thomas Cook”) and Redrow Plc (“Redrow”), (together
the “Companies”) which he did not intend to execute (the “Misleading Orders”),
on the opposite side of the order book to existing smaller orders which he intended
to execute (the “Genuine Orders”).
This Decision Notice was superseded by a Final Notice dated 15 December 2020:
2
2.2.
Through these large orders, Mr Abbattista falsely represented to the market an
intention to buy/sell when his true intention was the opposite. These orders gave
false and misleading signals as to demand/supply because Mr Abbattista did not
place them with a genuine intention that they should be executed.
2.3.
Given the Misleading Orders placed by Mr Abbattista were for volumes of shares
far greater than the typical market size, they would likely have had a material
impact on other market participants and would have created a false and
misleading impression regarding the true supply of and demand for the shares in
question.
2.4.
A feature of Mr Abbattista’s conduct was that he always placed the large
Misleading Orders such that their full size was visible to other market participants.
In contrast, when he placed the Genuine Orders he almost always placed them as
“Iceberg Orders”. An Iceberg Order is a permitted facility available to market
participants whereby the total amount of an order to buy or sell a security is
divided into a portion which is visible to other market participants, and a portion
which is hidden. This reduces the risk that the order will impact the price of the
security in question, whilst still allowing the market to see the direction in which
that trader wishes to trade. That he did not use this facility when placing the
Misleading Orders demonstrates that he wanted to maximise the impression
created by these orders.
2.5.
Where Mr Abbattista placed a large misleading buy order it would likely have
created the impression that there was a material buyer in the market. Where he
placed a large Misleading Sell Order it would likely have created the impression
that there was a material seller in the market. The number of shares in the
Misleading Orders were many multiples of both the part of the genuine Iceberg
Orders visible to the market and the visible order book average at the time.
2.6.
The identity of the person placing orders with the direct market access (“DMA”)
tools used by Mr Abbattista would be known only to the broker that was providing
the platforms and systems. Therefore, market participants would not have known
that Mr Abbattista had both buy orders and sell orders in the market at the same
time.
2.7.
Other market participants would likely have altered their trading strategies as a
result. Where he created the impression that there was a material buyer in the
market, other buyers, anticipating that the market was likely promptly to move
higher, would bid more for a security than in the absence of his misleading buy
3
order (and vice-versa). Other market participants were thereby misled about the
true state of supply and demand in the market.
2.8.
Mr Abbattista was aware of the risk that his actions might constitute market
manipulation, but recklessly went ahead with those actions anyway.
2.9.
The Authority has decided to take this action because:
(a)
during the Relevant Period Mr Abbattista engaged in market manipulation
as defined by Article 12(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation, by placing
the Misleading Orders which gave, or were likely to have given, false or
misleading signals as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the
Companies, in contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation;
and
(b)
as a result of his having recklessly engaged in market manipulation, he lacks
integrity and is not a fit and proper person to perform any function in relation
to any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt person, or
exempt professional firm.
2.10.
The Authority has therefore decided to:
(a)
impose on Mr Abbattista a financial penalty of £100,000, pursuant to section
123(1) of the Act, for engaging in market manipulation; and
(b)
make an order prohibiting Mr Abbattista from performing any function in
relation to any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt
person, or exempt professional firm, pursuant to section 56 of the Act.
3.
DEFINITIONS
3.1.
The definitions below are used in this Notice:
“the Act” means the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000;
“the Authority” means the Financial Conduct Authority;
“Best Bid” means the highest price at which a person was willing to buy the
security;
“Best Offer” means the lowest price at which a person was willing to sell the
security;
“CFD” means contract for difference, an agreement between a customer and a
financial institution, where the difference in the value of a specified asset at the
beginning and end of the contract is exchanged. To trade in these products a
customer need only deposit a small percentage of the value of the contract. In
the case of equities, these products allow customers to speculate on share price
movement without the need to buy the underlying shares;
“Colleague A” means the individual mentioned at paragraph 4.79, being a senior
colleague of Mr Abbattista;
“Companies” means Diageo, Ibstock, M&S, Redrow and Thomas Cook together;
“Dark Pool” means a trading platform with no pre-trade transparency as all orders
are hidden as to price and volume and are anonymous;
“DEPP” means the Decisions Procedures and Penalty Manual, part of the
Handbook;
“Diageo” means Diageo Plc;
“DMA” means direct market access and is an electronic trading facility that enables
investors in financial instruments to directly place orders and trade via the order
books of major exchanges;
“Fenician” means Fenician Capital Management LLP a firm formerly authorised by
the Authority (reference number 417507) which was dissolved on 26 March 2019;
“Funds” means two off shore hedge funds for which Fenician was appointed
investment manager, which in practice operated on the same investment
strategy;
“Genuine Orders” has the meaning set out at paragraph 2.1, and “Genuine Buy
Order” and “Genuine Sell Order” are to be interpreted accordingly;
“Handbook” means the Authority’s Handbook of Rules and Guidance;
“Ibstock” means Ibstock Plc;
“Iceberg Order” means an order to buy or sell a security where the total amount
of the order is divided into a visible portion, which is visible to other market
participants, and a hidden portion which is not. When the visible part of the order
is filled, a further part of the hidden portion of the same size becomes visible.
“Limit Order” means a type of order to purchase or sell a security at a specified
price or better. For buy Limit Orders, the order will be executed only at the limit
price or a lower one, while for sell Limit Orders, the order will be executed only at
the limit price or a higher one.
the “LSE” means the London Stock Exchange;
“MAR” means the part of the Authority’s Handbook of rules and guidance entitled
“Market Conduct”;
5
“the Market Abuse Regulation” means Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 of the
European Parliament and of the Council of 16 April 2014 on market abuse;
“M&S” means Marks and Spencer Group Plc;
“MiFID II” means Directive 2014/65/EU of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 15 May 2014 on markets in financial instruments;
“Misleading Orders” has the meaning set out at paragraph 2.1 above, and
“Misleading Buy Order” and “Misleading Sell Order” are to be interpreted
accordingly;
“Multilateral Trading Facility” or “MTF” means a trading venue that facilitates the
exchange of financial instruments between multiple parties;
“RDC” means the Regulatory Decisions Committee of the Authority (see further
at paragraph 8.3 below);
“Redrow” means Redrow Plc;
“the Relevant Period” means the period from 20 January 2017 to 15 May 2017;
“SOR” means the Smart Order Router system operated by the DMA provider which
processed Mr Abbattista’s DMA orders (see further paragraph 4.11 below);
“Thomas Cook” means Thomas Cook Group Plc;
“Touch” means the highest price to buy and the lowest price to sell; and
“the Tribunal” means the Upper Tribunal (Tax and Chancery Chamber).
4.
FACTS AND MATTERS
Fenician and Mr Abbattista
4.1.
Mr Abbattista was the founding partner and Chief Investment Officer at Fenician
which he founded in December 2004. During the Relevant Period, Fenician was
an investment management firm authorised by the Authority. During the Relevant
Period, Mr Abbattista was approved to perform the CF4 (Partner) and CF30
(Customer) controlled functions; he was also personally invested in the Funds.
4.2.
Mr Abbattista’s primary role was to manage and oversee the portfolio to meet the
investment goals and objectives of the Funds as well as to manage, with others,
the trading books for the investment portfolios of the Funds. He also chaired the
Investment Committee within Fenician which decided in which securities to invest,
in what amount, and the direction (i.e. whether as a seller or a buyer) of the
investment. As Chief Investment Officer, Mr Abbattista had the final say on such
decisions.
4.3.
During his time at Fenician, Mr Abbattista received compliance training from
external specialists appointed by the firm. This included refresher training in May
2016 which covered, amongst other matters, the regulations relating to market
abuse and gave examples of conduct that might constitute market manipulation,
including ‘orders removed before execution’ and ‘spoofing’ under examples of
transactions that might be false or misleading.
Fenician’s approach to investing
4.4.
The business of Fenician was managing the Funds, as long/short equity funds,
trading mainly in highly liquid European equities. The Funds’ investment decisions
followed a structured and considered process. An analyst or portfolio manager
would review a shortlist of stocks and conduct research, attend roadshows and
collate information. They would then prepare a report which would be presented
to the Investment Committee and a decision on whether to invest would be made.
4.5.
That decision would set out the proportion of the portfolio which would be invested
and the end target price. Usually those decisions were directional (i.e. one stock
either sold or bought; not both), or paired (two stocks, one bought and the other
sold, depending on their correlation). Once a decision to invest was made, the
decision of when and how to buy would rest with the portfolio managers. Fenician
did not consistently maintain Investment Committee minutes during the Relevant
Period. Those minutes that it maintained during 2016 do not provide any
meaningful record of its investment decisions in individual companies or
investment strategy generally.
4.6.
In general, 60% of the long/short investments were held for three to nine months,
although some stocks could be held for shorter or longer terms. Whilst Fenician
could engage in intra-day trading, it was not the Funds’ objective as a value
investor looking to achieve profits over several months. Opening a position with
the objective of unwinding it later that day was extremely rare and would only
occur where the market was very volatile; such circumstances did not arise at the
Funds during the Relevant Period.
Management and performance fees
4.7.
Fenician had two sources of revenue. The first was the management fee for
managing assets. The second was a performance fee if the Funds performed to a
particular standard. In the financial year 2016 to 2017 the Funds did not achieve
that standard and as a result Fenician received only its management fee. From
this all costs had to be paid before an allocation could be made to its members,
7
including Mr Abbattista. As a result, no allocation was made to Mr Abbattista for
that financial year.
Direct Market Access by Mr Abbattista
4.8.
Throughout the Relevant Period, Mr Abbattista placed the majority of his orders
and executed the majority of his trades using a direct market access (“DMA”)
system which was facilitated by a display screen. The screen would identify the
“Best Bid” (meaning the highest price at which a person was willing to buy the
security) and the “Best Offer” (meaning the lowest price at which a person was
willing to sell the security).
4.9.
It did not, however, show the hidden portion of any orders which were “Iceberg
Orders”. An Iceberg Order is an order to buy or sell a security where the total
amount of the order is divided into a portion which is visible to other market
participants, and a portion which is hidden. When the visible portion of the order
is filled, a further part of the hidden portion of the same size becomes visible. This
reduces the risk that the order will impact the price of the security in question,
whilst still allowing the market to see the direction in which that trader wishes to
trade.
4.10.
Through the display screen, Mr Abbattista could place an order to buy or sell a
CFD in a listed security. The order would be replicated by the DMA provider as an
order to buy or sell the security itself. In placing an order, he could manually
(a)
the volume he wished to buy or sell;
(b)
the price at which he wished to buy or sell; for example, he could specify
a particular price, state that he would accept a price up to a particular
limit, or accept whatever price was available in the market. The display
screen would show Mr Abbattista the Best Bid and Best Offer at the time
he was placing the trade. Generally, the further the price of an order is
away from the Best Bid or Best Offer, the less likely it is that such an
order will execute on a timely basis, or at all;
(c)
the way in which his order would display to the market; for example, he
could manually direct that his order should be entered as an Iceberg
Order; and
(d)
the duration for which his order would remain available; for example, he
could direct that it remain available until executed in full, he could direct
that whatever part of his order was not immediately executed should be
cancelled, or he could direct that any part of his order which had not been
executed by the close of trading that day should be cancelled.
4.11.
When Mr Abbattista placed an order the DMA system, in conjunction with an order
routing system (the “Smart Order Router” (“SOR”)) operated by the DMA
provider, would process the order as follows:
(a)
the system would first assess whether there was sufficient liquidity within
the Dark Pool associated with the system to execute all or part of the
order. If any such liquidity was available, the system would execute
whatever part of Mr Abbattista’s order it could;
(b)
for any remaining unexecuted volume (and subject to any Iceberg Order
placed by Mr Abbattista), the system would show that unexecuted volume
as available across four trading venues, namely: Turquoise, LSE, BATS
and Chi-x. The proportion of the order shown on each trading venue was
determined by an internal algorithm within the DMA system, taking
account of where the order was most likely to trade;
(c)
if the order was not an Iceberg Order, the full volume would be shown
from the beginning, albeit spread across the four trading venues. As
portions of the order executed, the volume visible to the market as
available would reduce; and
(d)
if a portion of the order was not visible to the market, as it was an Iceberg
Order, only the visible portion would be shown, again spread across the
four trading venues. As portions of the order executed, any volume
previously not visible to the market due to the Iceberg Order, would
replace the executed portion, such that the amount visible to the market
as available remained the same. This would continue until there was no
remaining volume not visible to the market, at which point executions
would reduce the volume visible to the market as still available.
4.12.
In practice, the splitting of the orders across the four trading venues did not
materially impact a typical market participant’s understanding of available volume
because many market participants view aggregated order books (albeit they could
view volume by individual platform should they so wish) which consolidate the
volume available on the four trading venues. This consolidated view is indicated
by the graphs in Annex C.
4.13.
During the Relevant Period, Fenician was only subscribed to DMA data feeds from
the LSE and not to feeds from the three other trading venues to which Mr
Abbattista’s orders might be directed. As a result Mr Abbattista’s DMA screen
would only display that volume of his orders that was directed to and placed on
the LSE (as indicated by the text below the graphs in Annex C). Market
participants would not be able to see the identity of the person placing the order.
4.14.
Any part of Mr Abbattista’s order which executed resulted in Fenician entering into
a CFD for the volume of shares in question, generally with the institution with
which the DMA system was associated. The counterparty would not become
aware of Mr Abbattista or Fenician’s involvement, even on settlement of the trade.
4.15.
On occasion Mr Abbattista, instead of using DMA, would use external brokers to
place orders. He did so through Bloomberg messages and by telephone.
4.16.
When market participants place orders into the market these can be placed at the
Best Bid or Best Offer price, or a number of price steps or increments away from
the Best Bid or Best Offer. These price increments are known as ticks. A tick size
is the smallest increment permitted in quoting or trading a security. Whist tick
sizes vary between primary exchanges and trading venues the market typically
follows the increments set by the primary exchange (in this Notice the LSE).
During the Relevant Period, for each stock mentioned in this Notice, the LSE
minimum tick sizes were as follows:
(a)
Thomas Cook – 0.05p
(b)
M&S, Ibstock and Redrow – 0.1p
(c)
Diageo – 0.5p
Mr Abbattista’s trading in M&S on 20 January 2017
4.17.
At the opening of the market on 20 January 2017, the Funds held a short position
in M&S of 200,000 shares, a position which they had held since 3 January 2017.
4.18.
While seeking to increase this short position through placing Genuine Sell Orders,
Mr Abbattista entered three large Misleading Buy Orders. His trading and
graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for M&S shares
during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.
Fenician’s investments in M&S
4.19.
The Funds maintained a short position of between 336,000 and 400,000 M&S
shares until 8 May 2017.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to M&S
4.20.
In the case of the buy orders, the placing of the orders indicated to the market
that a market participant wanted to buy between 150,000 to 250,000 M&S shares
at prices between 340.30p to 340.90p.
4.21.
In fact, Mr Abbattista did not want to buy this volume of M&S shares; furthermore,
the orders directly conflicted with the sell orders.
4.22.
That Mr Abbattista was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he
reduced his chances of executing the order by:
(a)
pricing such orders at 0.2p away from the existing Best Bid with at least
9,600 shares ahead of him, and
(b)
cancelling these orders after they had been available to execute for between
six to 18 seconds, a much shorter duration than the sell orders had been
available (between two minutes nine seconds and nine minutes seven
seconds).
4.23.
That Mr Abbattista was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact
that:
(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in M&S during
the days immediately following the trade, and
(b) the Funds did not substantially reduce their short position in M&S until
5 May 2017.
4.24.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was
greater genuine demand for M&S shares than was the case. The signals about the
volume of demand given by these orders were maximised because:
(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the
typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near
the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid
and offer; and
(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders; their full volume was therefore
immediately visible to the market.
4.25.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation
to the sell orders, genuine orders which he intended to and subsequently did
execute:
(a)
he manually specified a price for the sell orders which was equal to the Best
Offer, giving an improved chance of execution; and
(b)
he manually entered the sell order at 10:56:43 as an Iceberg Order
intending thereby to reduce the risk that the price of M&S shares would
move against him as the market reacted to his order.
Mr Abbattista’s trading in M&S on 8 May 2017
4.26.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar pattern of abusive conduct in relation to the
shares of M&S on 8 May 2017.
4.27.
At the opening of the market on 8 May 2017, the Funds held a short position in
M&S of 400,000 shares, a position which they had held since 14 April 2017. While
seeking to reduce this short position through placing Genuine Buy Orders, Mr
Abbattista entered several large Misleading Sell Orders. His trading and graphical
representations of the visible, consolidated market for M&S shares during this
sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.
Fenician’s investments in M&S
4.28.
Between 9 May and 11 May 2017, the Funds bought a further 200,000 M&S shares
thereby closing their position in full.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to M&S
4.29.
In the case of the sell orders, the placing of those orders indicated to the market
that a market participant wanted to sell between 150,000 and 200,000 M&S
shares at prices between 376.1p and 379.1p per share.
4.30.
In fact, he did not want to sell this volume of M&S shares; each of the sell orders
directly conflicted with one of the buy orders.
4.31.
That he was not a genuine seller is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his
chances of executing these orders by:
(a)
pricing such orders between 0.3p and 0.4p away from the existing Best Offer
with at least 15,000 shares ahead of him; and
(b)
cancelling such orders after they had been available for between four and
95 seconds, much shorter durations than the buy orders were available for
(between five minutes 32 seconds and four hours 12 minutes).
4.32.
That he was not a genuine seller is further demonstrated by the fact that:
(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further sell orders in M&S that
day, and
(b)
between 9 May and 11 May 2017, the Funds bought a further 200,000 M&S
shares thereby closing their position in full.
4.33.
Placing sell orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was
greater genuine supply of M&S shares than was the case. The signals about the
volume of supply given by the sell orders were maximised because:
(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the
typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near
the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid
and offer; and
(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.
4.34.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the sell orders contrast with those in relation
to the buy orders, genuine orders which he intended to and subsequently did
execute:
(a)
he manually specified a price for each of the buy orders which was close to
the Best Bid, giving an improved chance of execution; and
(b)
he manually entered the buy orders as Iceberg Orders intending thereby to
reduce the risk that the market would react to these orders by moving the
price of M&S shares against him.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive trading in other shares
4.35.
Mr Abbattista used a similar abusive strategy in the shares of the following
companies.
Diageo
4.36.
Mr Abbattista engaged in similar abusive conduct in relation to the shares of
Diageo on 26 January 2017.
4.37.
At the opening of the market on 26 January 2017, the Funds held a long position
in Diageo of 88,000 shares, a position which they had held since 16 January 2017.
While seeking to reduce his long position through placing a Genuine Sell Order,
Mr Abbattista entered four large Misleading Buy Orders.
4.38.
He placed the Genuine Sell Order by telephone or by Bloomberg through an
external broker. He placed all the Misleading Buy Orders using his DMA system.
His trading and graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for
Diageo shares during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.
Fenician’s investments in Diageo
4.39.
On 2 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Diageo shares.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Diageo
4.40.
In the case of the Diageo Misleading Orders, the placing of those orders indicated
to the market that a market participant wanted to buy between 30,000 and
50,000 Diageo shares at a price between 2237.50p and 2238.50p per share.
4.41.
In fact, he did not want to buy this number of Diageo shares; furthermore, each
of the buy orders directly conflicted with the sell order.
4.42.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his
chances of executing these orders by:
(a)
pricing them between 1p and 2p away from the existing Best Bid typically
with at least 13,000 shares ahead of him; and
(b)
cancelling these orders after they had been available to execute for between
almost four and 84 seconds, a much shorter duration than the sell order had
been available (nine minutes, 2 seconds).
4.43.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:
(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Diageo
that day, and
(b)
on 2 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Diageo shares.
4.44.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was
greater genuine demand for Diageo shares than was the case. The signals about
the volume of demand given by the buy orders were maximised because:
(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the
typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near
the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid
and offer; and
(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.
4.45.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation
to the sell order, a genuine order which he intended to and subsequently did
execute:
(a)
he changed the price of the sell order to bring it closer to the Best Offer
thereby giving an improved chance of execution; and,
(b)
the sell order was entered by the broker as an Iceberg Order.
4.46.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the
shares of Ibstock on 28 April 2017.
On 27 April 2017, the Funds began building a position in Ibstock by purchasing
400,000 shares, prior to which they had not held any position in Ibstock. While
seeking to increase this long position through placing a Genuine Buy Order, Mr
Abbattista entered a large Misleading Sell Order.
4.47.
The Genuine Buy Order was placed by telephone through a broker. The Misleading
Sell Order was placed by DMA. His trading and graphical representations of the
visible, consolidated market for Ibstock shares during this sequence of orders are
set out in Annex C.
Fenician’s investments in Ibstock
4.48.
By 4 May 2017 the Funds had increased their position in Ibstock to 800,000
shares, a position which they held until the end of May 2017.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Ibstock
4.49.
In the case of the sell order, the placing of this order indicated to the market that
a market participant wanted to sell 100,000 Ibstock shares at a price of 228.30p.
4.50.
In fact, he did not want to sell this number of Ibstock shares; furthermore, the
order directly conflicted with the purchase order. He did not inform the broker
about the existence of the sell order.
4.51.
That he was not a genuine seller is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his
chances of executing the order by:
(a)
pricing it 0.3p away from the existing Best Offer with at least 1,300 shares
ahead of him; and
(b)
cancelling it 36 seconds after he was informed that the buy order was being
partially filled, and when it had been available for execution for 4 minutes
55 seconds. The buy order took one hour 50 minutes to execute in full.
4.52.
That he was not a genuine seller is further demonstrated by the fact that:
(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further sell orders in Ibstock
that day, and
(b)
by 4 May 2017, the Funds had increased their position in Ibstock to 800,000
shares, a position which they held until the end of May 2017.
4.53.
Placing the sell order gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was
greater genuine supply of Ibstock shares than was the case. In fact, he was only
able to fill half of his buy order at this point. The sell order was cancelled leaving
the broker to execute the balance of the buy order in the market. The signal about
the volume of supply given by the sell order was maximised because it was not
placed as an Iceberg Order.
4.54.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the sell order contrast with those in relation
to the buy order, a genuine order which he intended to and subsequently did
execute:
(a)
he specified the price of the buy order at the Best Bid, giving an improved
chance of execution; and
(b)
he instructed that the buy order be processed within the current bid/offer
spread leaving the balance to work in the market, intending thereby to
reduce the risk that the market would react to his order by moving the price
of Ibstock shares against him.
4.55.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the
shares of Thomas Cook on 15 May 2017.
4.56.
At the opening of the market on 15 May 2017, the Funds had a long position in
Thomas Cook of 1,438,000 shares, a position which they had held since 30
December 2016. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing
Genuine Sell Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.
His trading and graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for
Thomas Cook shares during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.
Fenician’s investments in Thomas Cook
4.57.
On 16 May 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Thomas Cook shares.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Thomas Cook
4.58.
In the case of the buy orders, the placing of those orders indicated to the market
that a market participant wanted to buy 150,000 Thomas Cook shares at a price
of between 92.50p and 93.35p.
4.59.
In fact, he did not want to buy this number of Thomas Cook shares; furthermore,
the orders directly conflicted with the sell orders.
4.60.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his
chances of executing these orders by:
(a)
pricing them between 0.1p and 0.15p away from the existing Best Bid with
at least 11,000 shares ahead of him; and
(b)
cancelling such orders after they had been available for between four and
48 seconds.
4.61.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:
(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Thomas
Cook that day, and
(b) on 16 May 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Thomas Cook shares.
4.62.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was
greater genuine demand for Thomas Cook shares than was the case. The signals
about the volume of demand given by the buy orders were maximised because:
(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the
typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near
the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid
and offer; and
(b)
He did not place them as Iceberg Orders.
4.63.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation
to the sell orders, genuine orders which he intended to and did partially execute:
(a)
he manually specified a price for each of the sell orders which was close to
the Best Offer, giving an improved chance of execution; and
(b)
he manually entered the sell orders as Iceberg Orders.
4.64.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the
shares of Redrow between 24 and 27 February 2017.
4.65.
At the opening of the market on 24 February 2017, the Funds held a long position
in Redrow of 100,000 shares, a position which they had held since 15 February
2017. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing Genuine Sell
Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.
4.66.
Due to the number of orders that form part of this course of conduct they are
described below in summary only and without the inclusion of charts at Annex C.
4.67.
Between 24 and 27 February 2017, he entered a series of nine genuine orders
(“the Redrow Genuine Orders”) which indicated an intention to sell Redrow shares
and seven Misleading Orders (“the Redrow Misleading Orders”) which indicated
an intention to buy Redrow shares. Six out of the nine Redrow Genuine Orders
were placed as Iceberg Orders but none of the Redrow Misleading Orders were
placed as Iceberg Orders.
4.68.
On all but one occasion, at the time the Redrow Misleading Orders were placed,
he manually specified a price for those Misleading Orders which was further from
the relevant prevailing Best Bid than the distance of the Redrow Genuine Order
price from its then relevant prevailing Best Offer. There was one occasion when
the Misleading Order was placed closer to the Best Bid than the distance of the
Redrow Genuine Order priced from the Best Offer. In this instance both the
Misleading and Genuine Orders were subsequently cancelled without buying or
selling any shares.
Fenician’s investments in Redrow
4.69.
On 28 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining position in Redrow.
Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Redrow
4.70.
In the case of the Redrow Misleading Orders, the placing of those orders indicated
to the market that a market participant wanted to buy between 20,000 and
25,000 Redrow shares at prices between 484.6p and 488.1p per share.
4.71.
In fact, he did not want to buy this volume of Redrow shares; each of the Redrow
Misleading Orders directly conflicted with one of the Redrow Genuine Orders.
4.72.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his
chances of executing these orders by cancelling them after they had been
available to execute for between three and 18 seconds, much shorter durations
than the Redrow Genuine Orders which had been available for between 37
seconds and two hours and 40 minutes.
4.73.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:
(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Redrow
that day, and
(b)
on 28 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining position in Redrow.
4.74.
Placing the Redrow Misleading Orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression
that there was greater genuine demand for Redrow shares than was the case. The
signals about the volume of demand given by the Redrow Misleading Orders were
maximised because:
(a)
Mr Abbattista placed such orders for volumes of shares that were at least
double the volumes of his Genuine Orders; and
(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.
4.75.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the Redrow Misleading Orders contrast with
those in relation to the Redrow Genuine Orders, genuine orders which he intended
to execute. He manually placed six of the nine Redrow Genuine Orders as Iceberg
Orders.
Mr Abbattista’s explanation for his conduct
4.76.
Mr Abbattista has stated that the Misleading Orders were placed to give effect to
a particular trading technique, the primary purpose of which was to identify
“hidden liquidity” (i.e. liquidity that was not visible to him or the wider market
simply by looking at the order book) in order to gain market intelligence.
4.77.
Amongst a number of other features of the technique that he described was that
with his Genuine Order in place, he would place his “trial bid” (or offer) becoming
or matching the Best Bid price for the same equity, which was larger than the
standard size of order in the market at that time for the equity in question (those
orders described in this notice as Misleading Orders). He said he did so in order
to find out if there was a hidden seller in the market who was inclined to trade on
the Best Bid but who would only sell to a buyer of a sufficiently large size. He
explained that each trial bid (or offer) was a genuine bid (or offer), on which he
was prepared and able to trade at all times, at the Touch, in larger than standard
market size.
4.78.
In fact, as set out above and in Annex C, Mr Abbattista did not place any of his
trial bids (or offers) such that they became or matched the Best Bid or Best Offer
for the equity in question.
Mr Abbattista’s discussions with a colleague
4.79.
Mr Abbattista did not discuss the technique with colleagues before beginning to
use it; for example, in meetings of Fenician’s Investment Committee. However,
on three occasions from early 2017 to May 2017, Mr Abbattista mentioned
privately to Colleague A, a respected colleague of his, that he had placed bids in
front of selling orders, saying that he had done this to test liquidity. On the first
two occasions, Colleague A advised Mr Abbattista not to adopt that strategy; on
the final occasion, he told Mr Abbattista more directly that he should not do so,
as it might attract scrutiny from the exchange, the DMA provider or the regulator.
4.80.
Mr Abbattista agreed not to adopt the strategy again. The last Misleading Order
took place on 15 May 2017.
5.
FAILINGS
5.1.
The regulatory provisions relevant to this Notice are referred to in Annex A.
Article 2 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Scope)
5.2.
By virtue of Article 2(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation, its provisions apply to
financial instruments, as defined by Article 4(1)(15) of MiFID II, admitted to
trading on a regulated market, which defines a financial instrument as those
instruments specified in Section C of Annex I. This includes, amongst other
financial instruments, transferable securities. The definition of “regulated market”
in the Market Abuse Regulation derives from Article 4(1)(21) of MiFID II and
includes the LSE.
5.3.
Accordingly, the provisions of the Market Abuse Regulation apply to the shares of
the Companies.
Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Prohibition of market
manipulation)
5.4.
Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, as a result of Article 12(1)(a), prohibits
the placing of an order to trade which gives, or is likely to give a false or
misleading signal as to the supply of or demand for a UK listed share.
Article 12 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Market manipulation)
5.5.
Article 12(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation states that market manipulation
shall comprise the following activities (so far as relevant to this Notice):
“entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or any other behaviour
gives, or is likely to give, false or misleading signals as to the supply
of, demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, […];
unless the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or
engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order or
behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with
an accepted market practice as established in accordance with Article 13.”
5.6.
Mr Abbattista’s Misleading Orders were not carried out for legitimate reasons, nor
did they conform with an accepted market practice as established in accordance
with Article 13.
5.7.
Mr Abbattista engaged in market manipulation as defined by Article 12 and in
contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, as in placing the
Misleading Orders he gave, or is likely to have given, false and misleading signals
as to the supply or demand for the shares to which the Misleading Orders related.
This was because in placing the Misleading Orders Mr Abbattista signalled that he
wanted to buy or sell a specified number of shares. In fact, he did not wish to
trade in that manner.
5.8.
The Authority considers that, as an experienced market professional, Mr
Abbattista must have been aware of the risk that his actions might constitute
market abuse, in that his Misleading Orders would give false or misleading signals
to other market participants as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the
Companies, but recklessly went ahead with them anyway. He did not seek the
views of colleagues before starting to use the technique. Further, he did not heed
the misgivings expressed by Colleague A about the technique when he first
mentioned it privately to Colleague A. The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista
closed his mind to those misgivings, which should have caused him to consider
whether his actions were acceptable. He only ceased using the technique when
told by Colleague A directly that he should not use it.
Fitness and Propriety
5.9.
Mr Abbattista is not a fit and proper person to perform any function in relation to
any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt person, or exempt
professional firm. This is because his conduct in recklessly engaging in market
abuse lacked integrity.
6.
SANCTION
Financial penalty
6.1.
The Authority’s policy for imposing a financial penalty is set out in Chapter 6 of
DEPP. The Authority applies a five-step framework to determine the appropriate
level of financial penalty. DEPP 6.5C sets out the details of the five-step framework
that applies in respect of financial penalties imposed on individuals in market
abuse cases.
Step 1: disgorgement
6.2.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.1G, at Step 1 the Authority seeks to deprive an individual
of the financial benefit derived directly from the market abuse where it is
practicable to quantify this.
6.3.
The Authority has not identified any financial benefit that Mr Abbattista derived
directly from the market abuse. Step 1 is therefore £0.
Step 2: the seriousness of the breach
6.4.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.2G, at Step 2 the Authority determines a figure that
reflects the seriousness of the market abuse. That figure is dependent on whether
or not the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment. The
market abuse committed by Mr Abbattista was referable to his employment. In
cases where the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment, the
Step 2 figure will be the greater of:
(1)
a figure based on the percentage of the individual’s “relevant income”;
(2)
a multiple of the profit made or loss avoided by the individual for their own
benefit, or for the benefit of other individuals where the individual has been
instrumental in achieving that benefit, as a direct result of the market abuse
(the “profit multiple”); and
(3)
for market abuse cases which the Authority assesses to be seriousness level
4 or 5, £100,000.
6.5.
The Authority has not identified any profit made or loss avoided for Mr Abbattista’s
own financial benefit from the market abuse.
6.6.
An individual’s relevant income is the gross amount of all benefits they received
from the employment in connection with which the market abuse occurred for the
period of the abuse.
6.7.
The period of the market abuse committed by Mr Abbattista was from 20 January
2017 to 15 May 2017. Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.2(5), where the market abuse lasted
less than 12 months, the relevant income will be that earned by the individual in
the last 12 months preceding the final market abuse. Therefore, the relevant
period for calculating Mr Abbattista’s relevant income is the 12-month period
ending on 15 May 2017. Mr Abbattista’s relevant income in the 12-month period
ending on 15 May 2017 was £5249.14.
6.8.
In cases where the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment:
(1)
the Authority determines the percentage of relevant income which applies
by considering the seriousness of the market abuse and choosing a
percentage between 0% and 40%; and the Authority determines the profit
multiple which applies by considering the seriousness of the market abuse
and choosing a multiple between 0% and 40%.
(2)
The percentage range and profit multiple range are divided into five fixed
levels which reflect, on a sliding scale, the seriousness of the market abuse;
the more serious the market abuse, the higher the level. For penalties
imposed on individuals for market abuse there are the following five levels:
Level 1 – 0%, profit multiple of 0
Level 2 – 10%; profit multiple of 1;
Level 3 – 20%; profit multiple of 2;
Level 4 – 30%; profit multiple of 3; and
Level 5 – 40%; profit multiple of 4.
6.9.
In assessing the seriousness level, the Authority takes into account various factors
which reflect the impact and nature of the market abuse, and whether it was
committed deliberately or recklessly.
6.10.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(14) states that factors tending to show the market abuse was
committed recklessly include, amongst other factors, that the individual
appreciated there was a risk that his actions would result in market abuse and
failed adequately to mitigate that risk (DEPP 6.5C.2G(14)(a)); and the individual
was aware there was a risk that his actions could result in market abuse but failed
to check if he was acting in accordance with internal procedures (DEPP
6.11.
The Authority considers Mr Abbattista recklessly committed market abuse. It
considers that he was aware of the risk that his actions would result in market
abuse; i.e. that his Misleading Orders would give false or misleading signals to
other market participants as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the
Companies but went ahead with those actions anyway.
6.12.
Mr Abbattista’s market abuse was repeated on multiple occasions during the
Relevant Period.
6.13.
The Authority has also taken into account the following factors relating to the
nature of the market abuse:
(1)
Mr Abbattista is an experienced industry professional (DEPP 6.5C.2G
(12)(e)); and
(2)
Mr Abbattista held a senior position at Fenician where he was approved to
perform the CF4 (Partner) significant influence controlled function, in
addition to the CF30 (Customer) controlled function (DEPP 6.5C.2G (12)(f)).
He was also Fenician’s Chief Investment Officer.
6.14.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(15) lists factors likely to be considered ‘level 4 or 5 factors’. Of
these, the Authority considers the following factors to be relevant:
(1)
The market abuse was committed on multiple occasions during the Relevant
Period (DEPP 6.5C.2G(15)(c)); and
(2)
The market abuse was committed deliberately or recklessly (DEPP
6.5C.2G(15)(f)).
6.15.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(16) lists factors likely to be considered ‘level 1, 2 or 3 factors’. Of
these, the Authority considers the following factors to be relevant:
(1)
Little, or no, profits were made or losses avoided as a result of Mr
Abbattista’s
market
abuse,
either
directly
or
indirectly
(DEPP
6.5C.2G(16)(a).
6.16.
Taking all of these factors into account, the Authority considers the seriousness
of the market abuse to be level 4. This means the Step 2 figure is the higher of:
(1)
30% of Mr Abbattista’s relevant income of £5249.14, a sum of £1574.74;
(2)
A profit multiple of 3 applied to Mr Abbattista’s financial benefit of £0, a sum
of £0; and
(3)
£100,000.
6.17.
Step 2 is therefore £100,000.
Step 3: mitigating and aggravating factors
6.18.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.3G, at Step 3 the Authority may increase or decrease the
amount of the financial penalty arrived at after Step 2, but not including any
amount to be disgorged as set out in Step 1, to take into account factors which
aggravate or mitigate the market abuse. Having considered each of the factors
listed in DEPP 6.5C.3G, the Authority has concluded that there are no aggravating
or mitigating factors such as to justify an adjustment to the Step 2 figure.
6.19.
Step 3 is therefore £100,000.
Step 4: adjustment for deterrence
6.20.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.4G, if the Authority considers the figure arrived at after
Step 3 is insufficient to deter the individual who committed the market abuse, or
others, from committing further or similar market abuse, then the Authority may
increase the penalty.
6.21.
The Authority considers that the Step 3 figure of £100,000 represents a sufficient
deterrent to Mr Abbattista and others, and so has not increased the penalty at
Step 4. Step 4 is therefore £100,000.
Step 5: settlement discount
6.22.
The Authority and Mr Abbattista have not reached agreement to settle so no
discount applies to the Step 4 figure.
6.23.
The total financial penalty is therefore £100,000.
6.24.
The Authority has had regard to the guidance in Chapter 9 of EG in considering
whether to impose a prohibition order on Mr Abbattista. The Authority has the
power to prohibit individuals under section 56 of the Act.
6.25.
The Authority considers that, due to his having recklessly engaged in market
abuse, Mr Abbattista lacks integrity and is not a fit and proper person to perform
any function in relation to any regulated activity carried out by an authorised
person, exempt person or exempt professional firm. It considers that a prohibition
order should be imposed on him under section 56 of the Act.
7.
REPRESENTATIONS
7.1.
Annex D contains a brief summary of the key representations made by Mr
Abbattista, and how they have been dealt with. In making the decision which
gave rise to the obligation to give this Notice, the Authority has taken into account
all of the representations made by Mr Abbattista, whether or not set out in Annex
D.
8.
PROCEDURAL MATTERS
8.1.
This Notice is given to Mr Abbattista under section 57 and section 127 and in
accordance with section 388 of the Act.
8.2.
The following paragraphs are important.
Decision-maker
8.3.
The decision which gave rise to the obligation to give this Notice was made by the
RDC. The RDC is a committee of the Authority which takes certain decisions on
behalf of the Authority. The members of the RDC are separate to the Authority
staff involved in conducting investigations and recommending action against firms
and individuals. Further information about the RDC can be found on the
Authority’s website here: https://www.fca.org.uk/about/committees/regulatory-
decisions-committee-rdc
The Tribunal
8.4.
Mr Abbattista has the right to refer the matter to which this Notice relates to the
Tribunal. Under paragraph 2(2) of Schedule 3 of the Tribunal Procedure (Upper
Tribunal) Rules 2008, Mr Abbattista has 28 days from the date on which this
Notice is given to him to refer the matter to the Tribunal. A reference to the
Tribunal is made by way of a signed reference notice (Form FTC3) filed with a
copy of this Notice. The Tribunal’s contact details are: The Upper Tribunal, Tax
(tel: 020 7612 9730; email fs@hmcts.gsi.gov.uk). Further information on the
Tribunal, including guidance and the relevant forms to complete, can be found on
the HM Courts and Tribunal Service website:
8.5.
A copy of the reference notice (Form FTC3) must also be sent to the Authority at
the same time as filing a reference with the Tribunal. A copy of the reference
notice should be sent to Kerri Scott at the Financial Conduct Authority, 12
Endeavour Square, London E20 1JN. Once any referral is determined by the
Tribunal and subject to that determination, or if the matter has not been referred
to the Tribunal, the Authority will issue a Final Notice about the implementation
of that decision.
8.6.
If the person to whom this Decision Notice is given refers the matter to the
Tribunal, they may be eligible for legal assistance under section 134 of the Act.
Access to evidence
8.7.
Section 394 of the Act applies to this Notice.
8.8.
The person to whom this Notice is given has the right to access:
(1)
the material upon which the Authority has relied in deciding to give this
Notice; and
(2)
the secondary material which, in the opinion of the Authority, might
undermine that decision.
Confidentiality and publicity
8.9.
This Notice may contain confidential information and should not be disclosed to a
third party (except for the purpose of obtaining advice on its contents). Section
391(1) of the Act provides that neither the Authority nor a person to whom this
Notice is given or copied may publish the Notice or any details concerning it unless
the Authority has published the Notice or those details.
8.10.
However, the Authority must publish such information about the matter to which
a Decision Notice or Final Notice relates as it considers appropriate. Mr Abbattista
should be aware, therefore, that the facts and matters contained in this Notice
may be made public.
8.11.
For more information concerning this matter generally, contact Kerri Scott at the
Authority (direct line: 020 7066 4620 /email: kerri.scott@fca.org.uk).
Elizabeth France
Deputy Chair, Regulatory Decisions Committee
ANNEX A
RELEVANT LEGISLATIVE AND REGULATORY PROVISIONS
1.
RELEVANT LEGISLATIVE PROVISIONS
The Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (“the Act”)
The Authority’s statutory objectives
The Authority’s statutory objectives, set out in section 1B(3) of the Act, include the
integrity objective, which is protecting and enhancing the integrity of the UK
financial system and includes (amongst other matters) its not being affected by
contraventions by persons of Article 15 (prohibition of market manipulation) of the
Market Abuse Regulation.
Section 123 of the Act
123.— Power to impose penalties or issue censure
(1) The Authority may exercise its power under subsection (2) if it is satisfied
that—
(a) a person has contravened […] Article 15 (prohibition of market
manipulation) of the market abuse regulation; […]
(2) The Authority's power under this subsection is a power to impose a penalty
of such amount as it considers appropriate on the person.
Section 56 of the Act
Section 56 of the Act provides that the Authority may make an order prohibiting an
individual from performing a specified function, any function falling within a
specified description or any function, if it appears to the Authority that that
individual is not a fit and proper person to perform functions in relation to a
regulated activity carried on by an authorised person, exempt person or a person
to whom, as a result of Part 20, the general prohibition does not apply in relation
to that activity. Such an order may relate to a specified regulated activity, any
regulated activity falling within a specified description, or all regulated actives.
Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 (“the Market Abuse Regulation”)
1. This Regulation applies to the following:
(a) financial instruments admitted to trading on a regulated market or for which a
request for admission to trading on a regulated market has been made; …
Article 12: Market manipulation
1. For the purposes of this Regulation, market manipulation shall comprise the
following activities:
(a)
entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or any other
behaviour which:
(i)
gives, or is likely to give, false or misleading signals as to the supply
of, demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, […];
unless the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or
engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order or
behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with an
accepted market practice as established in accordance with Article 13.
2. The following behaviour shall, inter alia, be considered as market manipulation:
(c) the placing of orders to a trading venue, including any cancellation or
modification thereof, by any available means of trading, including by electronic
means, […], and which has one of the effects referred to in paragraph 1(a)
above or […] by:
(iii)
creating or being likely to create a false or misleading signal about
the supply of, or demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, in
particular by entering orders to initiate or exacerbate a trend;
Article 13: Accepted market practices
1. The prohibition in Article 15 shall not apply to the activities referred to in Article
12(1)(a), provided that the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to
trade or engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order
or behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with an
accepted market practice as established in accordance with this Article.
Article 15: Prohibition of market manipulation
A person shall not engage in or attempt to engage in market manipulation.
Annex I
A. Indicators of manipulative behaviour relating to false or misleading signals and
to price securing
For the purposes of applying point (a) of Article 12(1) of this Regulation, and
without prejudice to the forms of behaviour set out in paragraph 2 of that Article,
the following non-exhaustive indicators, which shall not necessarily be deemed, in
themselves, to constitute market manipulation, shall be taken into account when
transactions or orders to trade are examined by market participants and competent
(f)
the extent to which orders to trade given change the representation of
the best bid or offer prices in a financial instrument, […] or more generally
the representation of the order book available to market participants, and
are removed before they are executed; …
Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2016/522
Article 1: Subject matter and scope
This Regulation lays down detailed rules with regard to:
(2) the indicators of market manipulation laid down in Annex I to Regulation
Article 4: Indicators of manipulative behaviour
1. In relation to indicators of manipulative behaviour relating to false or misleading
signals and to price securing referred to in Section A of Annex I to Regulation (EU)
No 596/2014, the practices set out in Indicators A(a) to A(g) of Annex I to
Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 are laid down in Section I of Annex II to this
Regulation.
Section I of Annex II of Regulation (EU) 2016/522
6. Practices specifying Indicator A(f) of Annex I to Regulation (EU) No 596/2014:
(a) Entering of orders which are withdrawn before execution, thus having the
effect, or which are likely to have the effect, of giving a misleading impression
that there is demand for or supply of a financial instrument, […] – usually
known as ‘placing orders with no intention of executing them’. …
30
2.
THE AUTHORITY’S HANDBOOK OF RULES AND GUIDANCE
2.1. The part of the Authority’s Handbook of rules and guidance entitled “Market Conduct”
(“MAR”) provides guidance on the Market Abuse Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 (see
MAR 1.1.2G).
2.2. Chapter 1.6 of MAR is headed “Manipulating transactions”.
2.3. MAR 1.6.5G states that the following factors are to be taken into account when
considering whether behaviour is for legitimate reasons in relation to article 12(1)(a)
of the Market Abuse Regulation, and are indications that it is not:
(1) if the person has an actuating purpose behind the transaction to induce others
to trade in, bid for or to position or move the price of, a financial instrument;
(2) if the person has another, illegitimate, reason behind the transactions, bid or
order to trade; and
(3) if the transaction was executed in a particular way with the purpose of creating
a false or misleading impression.
2.4. MAR 1.6.6G states that the following factors are to be taken into account when
considering whether behaviour is for legitimate reasons in relation to article 12(1)(a)
of the Market Abuse Regulation, and are indications that it is:
(1) if the transaction is pursuant to a prior legal or regulatory obligation owed to a
third party;
(2) if the transaction is executed in a way which takes into account the need for the
market or auction platform as a whole to operate fairly and efficiently;
(3) the extent to which the transaction generally opens a new position, so creating
an exposure to market risk, rather than closes out a position and so removes market
risk; and
(4) if the transaction complied with the rules of the relevant trading venue about
how transactions are to be executed in a proper way (for example, rules on reporting
and executing cross-transactions).
2.5. MAR 1 Annex 2 “Accepted Market Practices” records that there are no accepted
market practices as established by the Authority in accordance with Article 13 of the
Market Abuse Regulation.
2.6. MAR can be accessed here: https://www.handbook.fca.org.uk/handbook/MAR/
The Fit and Proper Test for Approved Persons (“FIT”)
2.7. The part of the Authority’s Handbook entitled “The Fit and Proper Test for Approved
Persons” (“FIT”) sets out the criteria that the Authority will consider when assessing
the fitness and propriety of a candidate for a controlled function. FIT is also relevant
in assessing the continuing fitness and propriety of an approved person. FIT can be
accessed here:
2.8. FIT 1.3.1G states that the Authority will have regard to a number of factors when
assessing the fitness and propriety of a person. The most important considerations
will be the person’s honesty, integrity and reputation, competence and capability and
financial soundness.
Prohibition orders
2.9. The Authority’s policy in relation to prohibition orders is set out in Chapter 9 of the
Enforcement Guide (“EG”).
2.10. EG 9.1 states that the Authority may exercise this power where it considers that, to
achieve any of its statutory objectives, it is appropriate either to prevent an individual
from performing any function in relation to regulated activities or to restrict the
functions which he may perform.
Decisions Procedures and penalties manual (“DEPP”)
2.11. Chapter 6 of DEPP sets out the Authority’s statement of policy with respect to the
imposition and amount of financial penalties under the Act and can be accessed here:
https://www.handbook.fca.org.uk/handbook/DEPP/6/?view=chapter
The Enforcement Guide (“EG”)
2.12. The Authority’s approach to financial penalties and public censures is set out in
Chapter 7 of EG and can be accessed here:
ANNEX B
EXPLANATION OF TRADING TABLES
1.
The trading tables contained within this Notice at Annex C are based on consolidated
information from the four trading venues namely: LSE, Turquoise, BATS and Chi-X.
The orders submitted to and visible to the market at any point in time to the 1000th
of a second. By way of example, Table A is shown below and can be interpreted in
accordance with the following paragraphs.
2.
The left-hand side of the table (the “Bid” side) shows the visible order book in relation
to the purchase of shares.
3.
The top horizontal axis on the left-hand side is a measure of volume.
4.
The vertical axis on the left-hand size are the price points at which orders to buy
existed. For ease of use the tables show between top four and top five ‘Best Bids’
i.e. the highest four or five prices which buyers were prepared to pay for the shares
in question at that point in time.
5.
The bars on the chart show, for each of the price points, the volume of the
consolidated buy orders visible to the market. In order to demonstrate the position
taken by Mr Abbattista, the tables also identify what portion of the visible order was
attributable to him. This would not have been identifiable by any market participants.
6.
The volume of the orders directed by the SOR to the LSE trading platform and
therefore visible to Mr Abbattista on his display screen as a result of Fenician’s
subscription to the LSE’s data feed (see paragraph 4.13 of this Notice) is recorded
below each graph.
7.
The right-hand side of the table (the “Offer”1 side) shows the equivalent information
in relation to the sale of shares.
8.
The Best Bid in the example below is 340.40p and the Best Offer is 340.60p.
1 Labelled “Ask” in the table.
Table A
MR ABBATTISTA’S DETAILED TRADING AND MARKET VIEW TABLES
1.
At 10:56:43 Mr Abbattista placed a Genuine Sell Order for 28,000 shares. It was a
Limit Order for 340.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 340.40p – 340.60p. It
was an Iceberg Order such that only 10,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 340.40p – 340.50p,
and it was 0.10p away from the Best Offer (Table 1A). 9,381 shares of the order
were sold over the next 17 seconds.
Table 1A at 10:56:43.7842
2.
At 10:57:01 Mr Abbattista placed a Misleading Buy Order for 250,000 shares. It was
a Limit Order for 340.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market was 340.40p
– 340.50p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 250,000 shares were visible to the
market. This Misleading Buy Order was 25 times larger than that part of his Genuine
Sell Order visible to the market, and at least 10 times larger than the average size
of orders visible at that time. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid /
Best Offer became 340.50p – 340.60p, and it was 0.20p away from the Best Bid
(Table 1B).
2 Where the term ‘Ask’ is used in the charts in Annex C it has the same meaning as the term ‘Offer’
used in the narrative.
Table 1B at 10:57:01.193
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.30p, 76,425 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 81,719
shares at 340.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 340.60p, no shares were visible to
the LSE. The total number of shares on offer on the LSE at 340.60p was zero.
3.
Over the next nine seconds a further 18,109 shares were sold from the Genuine Sell
Order. The Misleading Buy Order was cancelled one second later without any of the
order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid
/ Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 340.40p – 340.60p.3
4.
At 11:13:50 a second Genuine Sell Order for 15,000 shares was entered into the
market. It was a Limit Order for 341.20p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market
was 341.10p – 341.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 15,000 shares were
visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer
became 341.00p – 341.10p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Offer (Table 1C).
3 Here and subsequently in this Notice “ticked lower” (or higher) means with reference to the spread at
the time the Misleading Buy (Sell) Order was entered.
5.
No shares in the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when a second Misleading Buy
Order for 150,000 shares was entered into the market at 11:14:00. It was a Limit
Order for 340.90p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market was 341.10p –
341.10p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
341.10p – 341.20p, and it was 0.20p away from the Best Bid (Table 1D).
Table 1D at 11:14:00:792
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.90p, 45,855 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 53,174
shares at 340.90p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 341.20p, 4,586 shares were visible
to the LSE. The total number of shares offered at 341.20p on the LSE was 8,957.
6.
The Misleading Buy Order was cancelled 18 seconds later without any of either it or
the Genuine Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled
the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 341.00p – 341.10p.
7.
No shares in the second Genuine Sell Order (at 341.20p) were sold. At 11:23:08 it
was cancelled and re-entered with a limit of 341.10p (Table 1E).
Table 1E: 11:23:08.561
8.
Eight seconds later at 11:23:17 a third Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares was
entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for 340.80p when the Best Bid / Best
Offer in the market was 341.00p – 341.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all
150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the
Best Bid / Best Offer became 341.00p – 341.10p, and it was 0.20p away from the
Best Bid (Table 1F). This Misleading Buy Order was 10 times larger than Mr
Abbattista’s Genuine Sell Order, and at least 10 times larger than the average size
of orders visible at that time.
Table 1F at 11:23:17.078
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.80p, 45,855 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 50,351
shares at 340.80p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 341.10p, 4,586 shares were visible
to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 341.10p was 6,023.
38
9.
Four seconds later, at 11:23:20, all 15,000 shares of the Genuine Sell Order at
341.10p were sold and the order completed. Three seconds later the Misleading Buy
Order for 150,000 shares was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At this
time the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked higher to 341.10p – 341.30p.
10.
At 09:10:15 Mr Abbattista entered a Genuine Buy Order for 100,000 shares. It was
a Limit Order for 375.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.50p – 375.70p. It
was an Iceberg Order, with only 5,000 shares visible to the market. When the order
entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 375.60p – 375.70p, and it was
the Best Bid (Table 2A). Over the next 40 seconds, no shares of the Genuine Buy
Order were bought.
11.
At 09:10:55 he entered a Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit
Order for 376.20p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.80p – 376.00p.90p. It
was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 375.80p – 375.90p,
and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2B).
Table 2B: 09:10:55.966
12.
Over the next five seconds 200 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought. Over
the same period and in the presence of the Misleading Sell Order, the Best Bid / Best
Offer ticked lower to 375.60p – 375.70p.4
13.
At 09:11:37, the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled and re-entered with a lower
offer price of 376.10p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.60 – 375.80p. When
the order entered the market the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 375.60p – 375.80p,
and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2C).
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.60p, 2,644 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 3,644 shares
on the buy side at 375.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.10p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.10p
was 47,859.
14.
At 09:12:30 the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled without any of the order being
filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer
in the market had remained 375.60p – 375.80p.
15.
At 09:12:50, the Genuine Buy Order was cancelled and re-entered with a new bid
price of 375.80p, when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.70p – 375.90p.
16.
The Genuine Buy Order continued to be filled, with a further 22,449 shares being
bought by 09:13:19. At this time, Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Sell
Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best
Offer was 375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares
were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best
4 Where the Best Offer / Best Bid is described as ‘ticking higher or lower in the presence of the Misleading
Buy (Sell) Order’ this is with reference to the period between the time it was placed and the time it was
cancelled.
Offer remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table
2D).
Table 2D: at 09:13:19.491
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,569 shares
on the buy side at 375.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.10p
was 45,766.
17.
A further 9,558 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought over the next 26
seconds. The Misleading Sell Order was cancelled at 09:13:52 without any of the
order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid
/ Best Offer in the market had remained 375.90p – 376.00p.
18.
No further shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought over the next 3 minutes
and 2 seconds.
19.
At 09:16:54, Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order which was again for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible
to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer
remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2E).
Table 2E: 09:16:54.902
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,838 shares
on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p
was 51,964.
20.
Over the next six seconds, a further 10,825 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were
bought.
21.
At 09:17:29, 35 seconds after being entered, the third Misleading Sell Order was
cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order
was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.80p –
375.90p. No further shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought.
22.
At 09:17:42, Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Sell Order for 150,000
shares. It was a Limit Order again for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
375.80p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible
to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer
remained 375.80p – 376.00, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Bid (Table 2F).
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order was the only order on the LSE on the buy side at 375.80p.
Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares were visible to the LSE. The
total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p was 52,039.
23.
Over the next four seconds, a further 18,880 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were
bought.
24.
At 09:17:52, 11 seconds after being entered, the fourth Misleading Sell Order was
cancelled without any of this order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order
was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 375.80p –
376.00p.
25.
Over the next 2 minutes 51 seconds, a further 32,460 shares of the Genuine Buy
Order were bought. At this point in time the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked higher
to 375.80p – 376.00p.
26.
At 09:22:36 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 376.40p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.00p –
376.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
376.00p – 376.10p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2G).
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,073 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 11,924 shares
on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.40p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.40p
was 52,276.
27.
23 seconds later, at 09:22:59, the remaining 5,628 shares of the Genuine Buy Order
at 375.80p completed. At this point and in the presence of the fifth Misleading Sell
Order, the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p.
28.
Three seconds later, at 09:23:02, the fifth Misleading Sell Order was cancelled
without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was
cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.70p –
375.90p.
29.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered five Misleading Sell Orders against the first
Genuine Buy Order. In two of the five instances, the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked
lower after they were entered, in the remaining three instances the Best Bid / Best
Offer remained the same.
30.
At 09:23:24 he entered a second Genuine Buy Order for 100,000 shares. It was a
Limit Order for 375.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.80p – 376.00p. It
was an Iceberg Order, with only 7,854 shares visible to the market (Table 2H).
31.
At 09:23:42 he entered a Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit
Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.90p – 376.00p. It was not
an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order
entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it
was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2I).
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,559 shares
on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of offered on the LSE at 376.30p was
49,824.
32.
Over the next 25 seconds, 17,203 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought. At
this point in time, and in the presence of the Misleading Sell Order the Best Bid /
Best Offer had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p. At 09:24:48 the Misleading Sell
Order was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading
Sell Order was cancelled the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to
375.80p – 375.90p.
33.
At 09:25:11 Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Sell Order for 150,000
shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.40p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.90p
– 376.10p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained
375.90p – 376.10p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2J).
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 12,641 shares
on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.40p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.40p
was 50,027.
34.
The Misleading Sell Order was cancelled six seconds later without any of either the
buy or sell order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled,
the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 375.90p – 376.10p.
35.
At 09:25:46 Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Sell Order, this time for
200,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 200,000 shares were visible
to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
375.80p – 375.90p, and it was 0.40p away from the Best Offer (Table 2K).
Table 2K: 09:25:46.750
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 6,879 shares
on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 56,280 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p
was 64,335.
36.
Over the next 42 seconds, a further 30,139 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were
bought. The third Misleading Sell Order was cancelled at 09:26:29 without any of
the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best
Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p.
37.
At 09:27:40 the Genuine Buy Order for the remaining 52,658 was reduced by 50,000
shares to become a buy order for 2,658 shares.
38.
At 09:28:02 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Sell Order for 200,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 376.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.00p –
376.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 200,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained
376.00p – 376.20p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2L). At
09:28:06 the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled without any of the order being
filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer
in the market had remained 376.00p – 376.20p.
39.
At 09:28:20, Mr Abbattista adjusted the bid price of the Genuine Buy Order to
376.10p.
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, zero shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
a total of 9,269 shares on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at
376.50p, 56,280 shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered
on the LSE at 376.50p was 62,710.
40.
At 09:28:35 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Sell Order, this time for 150,000
shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.10p
– 376.30p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained
376.10p – 376.30p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2M). The fifth
Misleading Sell Order was cancelled five seconds later at 09:28:40 without any of
the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best
Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 376.10p – 376.30p.
Table 2M: 09:28:35.477
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 376.10p, zero shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
a total of 3,398 shares on the buy side at 376.10p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at
376.60p, 42,210 shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered
on the LSE at 376.60p was 48,475.
41.
At 09:28:56 Mr Abbattista adjusted the bid price of the Genuine Buy Order to
376.30p which then executed in full.
42.
At 09:29:29 Mr Abbattista entered a new Genuine Buy Order for 50,000 shares into
the market. This was a Limit Order for 375.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
376.10p – 376.20p. None of this order was filled when at 10:11:20 it was joined by
an additional Genuine Buy Order for another 50,000 at a bid price of 378.60p when
the Best Bid / Best Offer was now 378.50p – 378.60p. It was an Iceberg Order, with
only 6,969 shares visible to the market. The order started to be filled, with 27,499
shares being bought by 10:14:35.
43.
At the same time, 10:14:35, Mr Abbattista entered a sixth Misleading Sell Order for
150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 379.10p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
378.70p – 378.80p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible
to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
378.60p – 378.70p, and it was 0.40p away from the Best Offer (Table 2N).
Table 2N: 10:14:35.286
NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 378.60p, 131 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr
Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,
that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 4,256 shares
on the buy side at 378.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 379.10p, 42,210 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 379.10p
was 50,856.
44.
At 10:14:58 Mr Abbattista cancelled the Misleading Sell Order without any of the
order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid
/ Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 378.60p – 378.70p. At 10:18:47 the
remaining 22,501 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought at 378.60p.
45.
Finally, at 13:41:05 the Genuine Buy Order for 50,000 shares at 375.80p was
cancelled without any of the order being filled.
46.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered six Misleading Sell Orders. In three instances,
the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked lower after they were entered. In three instances, it
remained unchanged.
47.
At the opening of the market on 26 January 2017, the Funds held a long position in
Diageo of 88,000 shares, a position which they had held since 16 January 2017.
While seeking to reduce his long position through placing a Genuine Sell Order, Mr
Abbattista entered four large Misleading Buy Orders.
48.
He placed the Genuine Sell Order by telephone or by Bloomberg through an external
broker. He placed all the Misleading Buy Orders using his DMA system.
49.
At 09:51:20 the broker entered a Genuine Sell Order for 20,000 shares. The price of
the order was amended to 2240.00p at 09:55:11 when the Best Bid / Best Offer was
2238.50p – 2239.50p (Table 3A). It was an Iceberg Order, with only 2,000 shares
visible to the market.
Table 3A: at 09:55:11.078
50.
At 09:55:39 Mr Abbattista entered a Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares. It was
a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p – 2240.00p.
It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 2239.50p –
2240.00p, and it was 2.0p away from the Best Bid (Table 3B).
Table 3B: at 09:55:39.946
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,057
shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, 2,000
shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at
2240.00p was 2,000.
51.
By 09:55:45, 4,000 shares of the Genuine Sell Order had been sold. At 09:56:11
the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the
time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market
had ticked lower to 2238.50p – 2239.00p.
52.
At 09:57:32 Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2238.50p –
2239.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
2239.00p – 2239.50p, and it was 1.5p away from the Best Bid (Table 3C).
Table 3C: at 09:57:32.993
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,956
shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero
shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at
2240.00p was 1,135.
53.
This order was cancelled and re-entered 16 seconds later at 09:57:48. It was a Limit
Order for 2238.00p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p – 2240.00p. It was
not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible. When the order entered the
market the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 2239.50p – 2240.00p.
54.
Three seconds later, a further 5,232 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were sold. At
09:58:56 the second Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order
being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best
Offer in the market had ticked lower to 2239.00p – 2240.00p.
55.
At 09:59:25 Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Buy Order for 30,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 2238.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p –
2240.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 30,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained
2239.50p – 2240.00p, and it was priced 1.0p away from the Best Bid (Table 3D).
Table 3D: at 09:59:25.099
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2238.50p, 9,654 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 11,411
shares on the buy side at 2238.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero
shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at
2240.00p was 500.
56.
Immediately the third Misleading Buy Order was entered, a further 3,570 shares of
the Genuine Sell Order were sold. At 09:59:43 the third Misleading Buy Order was
cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order
was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 2239.50p –
2240.00p.
57.
At 09:59:58, Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.00p –
2240.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became
2239.50p – 2240.00p, and it was 2.00p away from the Best Bid (Table 3E).
Table 3E: at 09:59:58.464
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,875
shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero
shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at
2240.00p was 500.
58.
One second later, the remaining 191 shares of the Genuine Sell Order was filled. At
10:00:02 the fourth Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order
being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best
Offer in the market had ticked higher to 2240.50p – 2241.00p.
59.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered four Misleading Buy Orders. In two instances,
the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked lower, in one case it ticked higher, and in one case
it remained unchanged.
60.
On 27 April 2017, the Funds began building a position in Ibstock by purchasing
400,000 shares, prior to which they had not held any position in Ibstock. While
seeking to increase this long position through placing a Genuine Buy Order, Mr
Abbattista entered a large Misleading Sell Order.
61.
The Genuine Buy Order was placed by telephone through a broker. The Misleading
Sell Order was placed by DMA.
62.
At 09:03:40 Mr Abbattista entered a Misleading Sell Order for 100,000 shares. It
was a Limit Order for 228.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 227.90p – 228.00p.
It was not an Iceberg Order and all 100,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 227.90p – 228.00p,
and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 4A).
Table 4A: at 09:03:40.276
NB: Of the Misleading Sell Order at 228.30p, 64,510 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 64,609
shares on the sell side at 228.30p.
63.
At 09:03:49 on a shared Bloomberg IB chat between the broker and Mr Abbattista,
the broker confirmed that he had a client who was a seller of Ibstock. Mr Abbattista
placed a Genuine Buy Order with the broker for 200,000 Ibstock shares at 227.90p.
He instructed the broker to approach the client directly rather than place the order
on the order book.
64.
At 09:07:59 the broker informed Mr Abbattista that 100,000 shares of the Genuine
Buy Order had been filled at 227.70p. At 09:08:35 Mr Abbattista cancelled the
Misleading Sell Order. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best
Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 227.80p – 228.00p. No shares had
been sold. The broker then continued to execute the remaining balance of 100,000
shares of the Genuine Buy Order in the market, filling it in full at 10:59:19.
65.
At the opening of the market on 15 May 2017, the Funds had a long position in
Thomas Cook of 1,438,000 shares, a position which they had held since 30 December
2016. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing Genuine Sell
Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.
66.
At 11:52:39 he entered a Genuine Sell Order for 250,000 shares. It was a Limit
Order for 93.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was an
Iceberg Order, with only 15,000 shares visible to the market (Table 5A). 55,727
shares were traded immediately and the order remained live.
Table 5A: 11:52:39.701
67.
At 11:53:33 he entered a Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit
Order for 93.35p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was not an
Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order
entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p, and it was
0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5B).
Table 5B: at 11:53:33.534
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.35p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 81,033
shares on the buy side at 93.35p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 7,460 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was
10,707.
68.
Over the next five seconds, a further 105,190 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were
sold. At this point in time, and in the presence of the Misleading Buy Order, the Best
69.
At 11:53:49 the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order being
filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer
in the market remained 93.45p – 93.50p. The Genuine Sell Order had 89,083 shares
left to fill and the order remained live.
70.
A further 13,530 shares were sold when at 11:54:44 a second Misleading Buy Order
for 150,000 shares was entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for 93.30p
when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.40p – 93.45p. It was not an Iceberg Order
and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the
market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.40p – 93.45p, and it was 0.10p away
from the Best Bid (Table 5C).
Table 5C: 11:54:44.922
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.30p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 74,907
shares on the buy side at 93.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 495 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was
4,043.
71.
Four seconds later the second Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of it
or the Genuine Sell Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was
cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked higher to 93.40p –
72.
A further 10,739 shares had been sold when at 11:58:37 Mr Abbattista entered a
third Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 93.30p when
the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all
150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the
Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p, and it was 0.15p away from the
Best Bid (Table 5D). At 11:58:59 the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without
any of it or the Genuine Sell Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order
was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 93.45p – 93.50p.
Table 5D: 11:58:37.724
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.30p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,819
shares on the buy side at 93.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 10,395 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was
14,908.
73.
A further 40,771 shares had been sold when at 12:01:15 a second Genuine Sell
Order for 250,000 shares was entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for
93.50p which matched the Best Offer at the time (Table 5E). It was an Iceberg Order,
with only 15,000 shares visible to the market. The balance of the first Genuine Sell
Order, 24,043 shares, remained in the market and was filled by 12.22.22.
Table 5E: 12:01:15.143
74.
A total of 173,938 shares of the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when at
12:26:16 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 93.35p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p.
It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p,
and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5F).
Table 5F: 12:26:16.829
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.35p, 63,464 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 82,511
shares on the buy side at 93.35p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 14,923 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was
14,923.
75.
Six seconds later the fourth Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of it
being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best
Offer in the market had remained 93.45p – 93.50p. The Genuine Sell Order had one
fill of 66 shares over the period the fourth Misleading Buy Order was live.
76.
A further 60,557 shares of the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when at
13:51:05 the price of the remaining 15,505 shares was amended from 93.50p to
92.75p. The Best Bid at the time was 92.75p and the order was filled immediately.
77.
At 14:22:53 Mr Abbattista entered a third Genuine Sell Order for 250,000 shares. It
was a Limit Order for 92.95p. It was an Iceberg Order, with only 15,000 shares
visible to the market (Table 5G). No shares were sold when at 14:54:08 the price of
the sell order was amended to 92.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p –
92.85p. 34,517 shares of the order traded and the order remained live.
Table 5G: 14:22:53.699
78.
At 15:21:02 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order was for 92.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.70p –
92.80p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the
market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained
92.70p – 92.80p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5H).
Table 5H: 15:21:02.821
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.60p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,726
shares on the buy side at 92.60p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.80p, 10,733 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 92.60p was
15,479.
79.
Over the next 28 seconds, a further 44,843 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were
sold. At this time, and in the presence of the buy order, the Best Bid / Best Offer had
ticked higher to 92.75p – 92.80p. At 15:21:50 the fifth Misleading Buy Order was
cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order
was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked higher to 92.75p –
92.80p. At 16:02:33 the third Genuine Sell Order completed.
80.
At 16:04:10 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Genuine Sell Order for 288,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 92.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p – 92.80p
(Table 5I). It was an Iceberg Order, with only 20,000 shares visible to the market.
101,756 shares of the order traded and the order remained live.
Table 5I: 16:04:10.784
81.
At 16:15:40 Mr Abbattista entered a sixth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.
It was a Limit Order for 92.65p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p – 92.80p.
It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When
the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 92.75p – 92.80p,
and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5J).
Table 5J: 16:15:40.598
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.65p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,711
shares on the buy side at 92.65p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.80p, 8,156 shares
were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 92.80p was
82.
Over the next nine seconds, a further 21,783 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were
sold. At this time, and in the presence of the Misleading Buy Order, the Best Bid /
Best Offer remained 92.75p – 92.80p. At 16:16:02 the sixth Misleading Buy Order
was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy
Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 92.75p –
92.80p. The fourth Genuine Sell Order had 164,461 shares to sell and the order
remained live.
83.
At 16:21:53 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Genuine Sell Order for 4,461 shares. It
was a Limit Order for 92.65p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.60p – 92.65p
(Table 5K). It was not an Iceberg Order and all 4,461 shares were visible to the
market.
Table 5K: 16:21:53.760
84.
At 16:22:02 the fourth Genuine Sell Order was amended and the balance of 164,461
shares was reduced by 4,461 shares to 160,000 shares. The Limit Order remained
at 92.80p. The Best Bid /Best Offer was 92.60p - 92.65p. It was an Iceberg Order,
with only a maximum of 20,000 shares visible to the market. At this time 19,064
shares were visible to the market. At 16:22:43 the fifth sell order of 4,461 shares at
92.60p completed.
85.
At 16:25:40 the amended fourth Genuine Sell Order of 160,000 shares at 92.80p
was amended again to a new limit of 92.70p. The Best Bid/Best Offer was 92.65p -
92.70p. It was an Iceberg Order, with only 20,000 shares visible to the market.
7,662 shares of the order trade and the order remained live.
86.
At 16:27:38 Mr Abbattista entered a seventh Misleading Buy Order for 150,000
shares. It was a Limit Order for 92.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer at the time
was 92.60p – 92.70p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were
visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer
remained 92.60p – 92.70p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5L). The
Misleading Buy Order was cancelled six seconds later without any of it or the genuine
sell order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best
Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 92.60p – 92.70p. Mr Abbattista did not enter
any further buy orders that afternoon.
Table 5L: 16:27:38.730
NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.50p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.
Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the
LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 116,658
shares on the buy side at 92.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.70p, 6,025
shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at
92.70p was 18,311.
87.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered seven Misleading Buy Orders. In two instances,
the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked higher and in the other five it remained unchanged.
ANNEX D
REPRESENTATIONS
1.
Mr Abbattista’s representations (in italics), and the Authority’s conclusions in
respect of them, are set out below.
The orders in question were a legitimate trading technique
2.
In placing the relevant orders (referred to by the Authority in this Notice as
“Misleading Orders”) Mr Abbattista was using a legitimate trading technique of
liquidity testing. They were trial orders to help him assess the true state of liquidity
in a market environment where visible liquidity had dramatically declined. He used
them to determine whether there were hidden block traders who wanted to trade
in large size only but whose presence could not be seen by looking at the visible
order book. He would do this when he had an existing (“resting”) order on the other
side of the book, which was not being filled as quickly as he expected given the
normal liquidity of the stock in question.
3.
In order to detect traders trading in larger than usual size, Mr Abbattista placed his
trial orders in larger than usual size. He chose not to apply the Iceberg Order
feature to them, because it would have made them appear smaller than they were.
But he thought (mistakenly) that the SOR which he used was automatically applying
the Iceberg Order feature, because the orders showed in smaller size than he was
expecting to see: they usually showed as a quarter to a third of what he expected.
He only had access to data showing the position on LSE and he now understands
that the orders were in fact routed to three other trading venues as well, so the
orders were split across all four. The size of the trial orders took account of the
Iceberg Order he thought was automatically being applied.
4.
Mr Abbattista placed his trial orders close to the Touch. In deciding where the Touch
was, he might discount small orders at the front of the order book because, from
his experience, these were likely to be ephemeral orders placed by high-frequency
algorithmic traders that were not representative of meaningful buying or selling
interest. He regarded these as “noise” in the market rather than representing where
the Touch really was. This view is supported by the view of an expert instructed
by him, who said that most professional traders recognise them as weak place-
holders that most likely will be cancelled quickly if one tries to hit or lift more than
one of them.
5.
Also, it is likely there would have been some variation between where the Touch
appeared to Mr Abbattista to be on the basis of orders placed on the LSE only
(which is all that he could see), and where it was on the basis of all four of the
trading venues to which Mr Abbattista’s orders could have been routed.
6.
Mr Abbattista expected that hidden block traders would be likely to be using trading
algorithms that would have executed against his trial order almost immediately.
As a result, he often cancelled his trial order if it had not been executed after a few
seconds, having obtained the knowledge he was seeking, namely that there was
no hidden block liquidity in the market. Conversely, if it had been traded, this would
also have been valuable intelligence that would have informed his approach to
trading the stock in question. As his resting order would typically have been
partially executed prior to his placing the trial order, he would generally have made
a small profit if his trial order had been executed, which would effectively have
been day trading in that stock. In some cases, this was a secondary motivation for
the trial order, in which case he might have let it rest for longer before cancelling
it. He may also have had in mind that by letting the trial order rest for longer, he
would be able to detect hidden block traders who were trading manually rather
than via an algorithm and may have taken longer to trade.
7.
Expert evidence obtained by Mr Abbattista showed that the practice of seeking
information about market liquidity by placing orders in this way is a common and
widely accepted practice.
8.
The trial orders were genuine. Mr Abbattista intended them to be executed by
hidden block traders if they were present in the market. It was only by being
executed that a trial order could reveal the presence of a hidden block trader.
Equally, the absence of execution within a certain period of time would provide
information about the likely absence of such hidden traders. The orders were open
to execution in whole or part from the moment they were placed, and were placed
at price levels and for lengths of time that meant they were at genuine risk of
execution. They were within the limits within which Mr Abbattista was permitted
to trade. He believed they could have been executed in the Dark Pool operated by
the DMA Provider, as well as in the “lit” (visible) market. In any event, there is no
legal distinction between “intending to trade” and being “prepared to trade”. This
is supported by the judgment in Sarao v Government of the United States of
America [2016] EWHC 2737 (Admin) which held that trades placed with the
intention that they be “open to acceptance” do not constitute “spoofing”.
9.
The Authority does not accept a number of Mr Abbattista’s representations about
the Misleading Orders. It considers it unlikely that a trader of Mr Abbattista’s
considerable experience would not have understood how the SOR worked, including
that it routed orders to more than one market. Further, the Authority notes that
Mr Abbattista told the Authority that his SOR screen had been configured on a
bespoke basis at his request, and that he had trialled the DMA system of another
provider on one occasion, as he wished to try out the service it offered. In the
Authority’s view, both these facts are inconsistent with a lack of interest in, or
understanding of, how the system worked. Had he misunderstood how the SOR
worked, the Authority also considers it implausible that Mr Abbattista would have
thought the reason only a portion of the Misleading Orders showed on his LSE feed
was that the SOR was automatically applying the Iceberg Order feature to them.
Were this the case, his Genuine Orders would also have shown in much smaller
than expected size after applying the Iceberg Order feature to them, and he could
be expected to have realised that the feature could not be the explanation for this.
Nor has Mr Abbattista offered any explanation for why, if he thought the Iceberg
Order feature was being applied automatically, he nevertheless manually selected
it for his Genuine Orders (as he has not suggested that he thought it would be
applied only to the Misleading Orders; nor is there any obvious logical basis for
such a belief). He has stated that he understood that, unless he manually applied
the feature by entering the size to be displayed, the size of the portion shown would
be determined by the SOR. He has not offered an explanation for why he did not
therefore seek to manually adjust the size displayed in relation to the Misleading
Orders. Nor has he explained why he did not seek to validate his surmise that the
feature was being applied automatically, or investigate whether the supposed
automatic feature could be disabled. Taking all these matters into account, the
Authority considers Mr Abbattista was aware that the Misleading Orders would show
in very large size to many market users.
10.
Nor does the Authority accept Mr Abbattista’s explanation for where the Misleading
Orders were placed in relation to the Touch. It notes that he first stated to the
Authority that they were at the Touch, whereas in fact none of them were. The
Authority’s examination of data showing on the LSE-only feed suggests that this
did not give a different impression of where the Touch was than the feed showing
data from all four exchanges. The Authority notes that it did not prevent Mr
Abbattista from either placing the Genuine Orders in almost all cases at the Touch
or improving it. Nor, in most cases, were the Misleading Orders in fact close to the
Touch, as Mr Abbattista now says was the case: most were more than one tick
away from the Touch, and many were several ticks away. Further, the Authority
does not accept that Mr Abbattista would in fact discount small orders at the front
of the order book to decide where the Touch really was, as he suggested might
have been the case; it notes that this approach does not appear to have informed
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the Genuine Orders.
11.
The Authority also notes that, on occasion, Mr Abbattista maintained his Misleading
Orders three or four ticks away from the Touch when it moved towards them: see
paragraphs 10 to 46 of Annex C. The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista
deliberately placed the Misleading Orders away from the Touch.
12.
The Authority notes that, while the experts’ reports provided by Mr Abbattista to
the Authority generally supported the view that seeking information about market
liquidity through the placement of orders is a common and widely accepted practice
(which the Authority does not dispute), they were not asked to express an opinion
on specifically whether what Mr Abbattista was doing when placing the Misleading
Orders was either common or widely accepted. One of the experts did, however,
express the view that it was a “usual” practice to use an order on the opposite side
of the book to the intended trade to test liquidity. But the Authority notes that Mr
Abbattista presented the technique as one he had developed; that Colleague A did
not support the technique’s use; and that the Authority’s own expert did not
consider the technique to be “usual”. The Authority does not accept that Mr
Abbattista’s technique conforms to any usual practice.
13.
The Authority considers that the large size of the Misleading Orders was
inconsistent with an intent on Mr Abbattista’s part that they should be filled, in
circumstances where he had a smaller open order (a Genuine Order) on the other
side of the order book, with which he was seeking to increase or reduce a position
in the relevant stock in accordance with a pre-determined investment strategy. Had
they been filled, that strategy would have been undermined by a substantial change
in the holding of that stock in the opposite direction to that intended. Day trading
was not part of Fenician’s overall strategy, and there is no evidence to suggest that
day trading was ever done by Mr Abbattista during the Relevant Period;
accordingly, the Authority does not accept it was a secondary aim of his in placing
the Misleading Orders.
14.
The Authority accepts that the Misleading Orders were at risk of execution, in the
sense that they were on the order book and could, theoretically at least, have been
filled. But the Authority considers that risk was small given their distance from the
Touch and the relatively short periods of time for which they remained open (much
shorter, in general, than the Genuine Orders). As noted above, the Authority
considers Mr Abbattista deliberately placed the Misleading Orders away from the
Touch. It also considers that he cancelled them relatively quickly to reduce the
chance of them being filled.
15.
The fact that the Misleading Orders were within Mr Abbattista’s permitted trading
limits is not an indication that he intended them to be filled.
16.
In conclusion, the Authority considers that Mr Abbattista did not intend the
Misleading Orders to be fulfilled, although he took the small risk that they might
be. This conclusion is supported by the fact that none of the orders was in fact
filled. Contrary to Mr Abbattista’s representation, there is a significant distinction
between being prepared to trade, in the sense of accepting a risk of trading, and
intending to trade. The Sarao case, cited by Mr Abbattista, in fact distinguished
between “(1) … placing an offer which at the time it is placed is intended by the
offeror to be open for acceptance, though it might subsequently be cancelled prior
to acceptance; and (2) … placing an offer which, at the time it is placed, the offeror
does not genuinely intend should be accepted”. It is not authority for the
proposition that an order which is available for acceptance, even if not intended to
be accepted, is not abusive.
17.
In the light of the Authority’s view that Mr Abbattista did not intend them to be
fulfilled, it considers the Misleading Orders constituted market abuse.
No reason to think the technique was abusive
18.
Mr Abbattista had no reason to believe that the trial order technique was not
permissible under the market abuse regime. At the time, there were no published
Authority cases or guidance indicating that placing live, at-risk orders in larger than
standard size (compared to the surrounding visible orders but small in comparison
to daily trading volume or large institutional orders) with a view to obtaining
information about hidden liquidity constituted market manipulation. Mr Abbattista
clearly recalls that the compliance training he had received in relation to market
manipulation focused on cases involving complex layering of the order book using
algorithms, such as the Authority’s previous decision in the Michael Coscia case,
rather than the liquidity probing technique he deployed.
19.
The Authority implicitly conceded it was not clear to the market, at the time Mr
Abbattista placed his trial orders, that it would consider such behaviour to be
abusive, when proposing to publish a Warning Notice Statement: it argued this
would be beneficial to enable market users to understand that the type of market
abuse engaged in by Mr Abbattista was unacceptable, and would encourage more
compliant behaviour.
20.
In the circumstances, it would be manifestly unfair to conclude that the trading
technique was prohibited, as this would amount to the retrospective issue of market
guidance.
21.
The Authority has set out above its views on the relative size of the Misleading
Orders, and the extent to which they were “at-risk”, and it comments on the
appropriate size comparators below. The Authority also notes the indicator of
manipulative behaviour set out at paragraph 6 of Section I of Annex II of Regulation
(EU) 2016/522: see Annex A to this Notice. It does not consider that it was
necessary for there to have been Authority published cases or guidance specifically
addressing the trading technique employed by Mr Abbattista for it to have been
clear to market users that the placing of orders with no intention of executing them
was unacceptable behaviour. Accordingly, the decision set out in this Notice does
not constitute retrospective “market guidance”. (The Authority further explains its
conclusions on Mr Abbattista’s state of mind below.)
22.
Enabling understanding by market users of unacceptable behaviour is expressly
stated (in Authority guidance in EG 6.2.5) to be a benefit of warning notice
statements. The fact that it was cited by the Authority in this case does not equate
to an implicit concession that it was not previously clear that the behaviour in
question was market abuse.
No false or misleading signals as to supply or demand for the relevant shares
23.
The trial orders did not give any signals to the market beyond the information they
conveyed on their face, namely that for as long as they remained open, if they were
hit or lifted (as applicable), a market participant would buy or sell (as applicable)
the relevant shares at the specified price in the visible volume; this was the case.
They did not convey any information about the strength of Mr Abbattista’s desire
to execute the orders. The proposition that an order does not give any further
representation is supported by expert evidence produced by Mr Abbattista.
24.
To the extent it is possible for an order to give signals to the market beyond the
information conveyed on its face, the trial orders did not do so. In particular, they
were not placed in sufficient size or with sufficient frequency (e.g. by the use of
computer algorithms to effect deep, fast, agile and consistent “layering” of the
order book) for other market participants to draw any other inferences about the
state of supply or demand for the shares in question.
25.
The Authority has used an inappropriate measure in evaluating whether the size of
the trial orders was large enough to create an impression on the market, namely
the size of other orders visible in the market at that time. It is widely understood
that the visible order book does not accurately represent the true state of supply
and demand in the market at any point in time (because of the use of Iceberg
Orders and other hidden order types). The trial orders were small in comparison to
the daily trading volumes of the relevant stocks and to large institutional orders.
26.
Insofar as the trial orders gave any signals to the market as to supply and demand
for the relevant shares, those were not false or misleading, because they were
genuine orders.
27.
The Authority has not adduced any evidence that market participants were in fact
misled, which suggests that they were not.
28.
As a result, Mr Abbattista has not committed market abuse.
29.
Mr Abbattista has not offered any justification for the proposition that daily trading
volume or large institutional orders are more appropriate comparators than the
surrounding orders on the order book when considering the relative size and effect
of the Misleading Orders. In the Authority’s view, it is clear that the effect of an
order is to be considered in relation to the changes to the representation of the
order book at the time it is placed. Indeed, this is specifically stated in Annex I
A(f) to the Regulation to be one of the indicators of manipulative behaviour relating
to false or misleading signals and price securing: see Annex A to this Notice. Daily
trading volume and large institutional orders (not present on the book at the
relevant time) are irrelevant. The Authority notes that the expert evidence relied
upon by Mr Abbattista expressed the view that medium-to-large size orders would
move the market and alter the behaviour of other market participants.
30.
The Authority has explained above why it does not consider the Misleading Orders
to have been “genuine”, in the sense that Mr Abbattista did not intend them to be
executed.
31.
It is not necessary to adduce evidence as to how specific market participants were
in fact misled by the Misleading Orders. The Authority considers that it is clear that
market participants were, or were likely, to have been, misled by them, so as to
satisfy the definition of market manipulation in Article 12 of the Market Abuse
Regulation.
If Mr Abbattista did commit market abuse, he can only have done so negligently
32.
The Authority cites, as a basis for its case against Mr Abbattista, the concerns
expressed by Colleague A to Mr Abbattista when they discussed the latter’s trading
technique. In fact, as appears from the transcript of the Authority’s interview with
Colleague A, the latter did not consider that there was anything wrong with the
technique. He appeared anxious (as he was prone to be) and so Mr Abbattista
stopped using the technique out of respect for Colleague A’s feelings. Also, the
technique was not proving to be of any particular value, so he accepted that
markets had changed forever and there was no point in continuing.
33.
This is to be contrasted with the previous case of Paul Axel Walter. As appears from
the Authority’s Final Notice in that case, Mr Walter was held to have committed
market abuse negligently, not recklessly, notwithstanding that he had received a
telephone call querying the trades in question. The Authority must act consistently:
if Mr Walter was negligent in not taking the broker’s concerns seriously, Mr
Abbattista can at worst have been negligent in not taking his own colleague’s
concerns more seriously.
34.
The Authority considers that, as an experienced market professional, Mr Abbattista
must have been aware of the risk that placing orders which he did not intend to be
fulfilled would be market abuse, but recklessly placed them anyway. Further, in
these circumstances, it considers that Colleague A’s expressions of concern about
Mr Abbattista’s technique early in the Relevant Period were a warning that the
technique might be unacceptable. In failing to heed this warning, the Authority
considers that he was closing his mind to the risk that the technique was abusive.
35.
The Authority has reached its view as to Mr Abbattista’s state of mind after
consideration of all the available evidence in this case, and the fact that a different
decision was reached in the Walter case, on different facts, does not undermine its
conclusion in this case. It notes that a relevant factual distinction between the
facts in the Walter case and the facts of this case (apparent from the Notice in that
case) is that the call in which concerns were expressed to Mr Walter was from a
third party unknown to him, and Mr Walter’s position was that he believed it to be
a hoax. In contrast, the concerns expressed to Mr Abbattista were from a senior
colleague for whom he has professed respect.
A prohibition is not appropriate
36.
Even if, contrary to his position, Mr Abbattista’s actions are found to have
contravened Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, based on the precedent
cases and relevant Authority guidance it is not appropriate to impose a prohibition.
37.
The case law on the use of prohibition orders has established that, in cases where
there has been no dishonesty or lack of integrity (including recklessness) their use
should be confined to the most serious cases of lack of competence, in which the
individual poses a risk to the public in future: see Timothy Alan Roberts, Andrew
Wilkins v The Financial Conduct Authority [2015] UKUT 0408. To the extent he is
found to have lacked competence in using the trading technique, Mr Abbattista
poses no such risk. The Authority’s enforcement action against him has affected
him very deeply, having had a profound impact on his life over a period of years,
and he has resolved never to use the trial order technique (or any similar technique)
again.
38.
This is not a case of lack of competence. The Authority has found that Mr Abbattista
acted recklessly, and therefore with a lack of integrity. For the reasons set out
above, it considers the imposition of a prohibition order in this case to be
appropriate, and in line with Authority guidance.
Financial penalty
39.
If, contrary to his position, the Authority considers that Mr Abbattista committed
market abuse, the Authority should consider the following. Although the technique
was used on multiple occasions, this was in circumstances where Mr Abbattista had
no reason to believe that it was not legitimate. None of the other “Level 4 and 5”
factors set out in DEPP 6.5C apply; accordingly, this cannot be a Level 4 or Level 5
case.
40.
The “Level 1 – Level 3” factors in DEPP 6.5C are as follows:
(a) little, or no, profits were made or losses avoided as a result of the market
abuse, either directly or indirectly;
(b) there was no, or limited, actual or potential effect on the orderliness of, or
confidence in, markets as a result of the market abuse; and
(c) the market abuse was committed negligently or inadvertently.
All those factors are present in this case; accordingly, this must be a Level 1 –
Level 3 case.
41.
The following mitigating factors should be taken into account, in accordance with
DEPP 6.5C.3(b), (f) and (h):
-
Mr Abbattista has co-operated with the Authority’s investigation from the very
beginning, including by volunteering a clear, detailed and thorough explanation
of his trading technique;
-
he has no regulatory disciplinary findings against him; and
-
there was no relevant Authority guidance or case law from which he could
reasonably have inferred that the trading technique was not permissible.
42.
The Authority should also take into account the profound impact the long
investigative process has had on the life of Mr Abbattista and his family. Mr
Abbattista has endured the significant personal pressures of being subject to an
Authority enforcement investigation, and has been unable to work during this
period, resulting in a significant loss of income.
43.
The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista committed the market abuse recklessly,
which is a further Level 4 or Level 5 factor. It follows that factor (c) in paragraph
40 above is not present in this case. The Authority does not agree that factor (b)
is present.
44.
The Authority considers the degree of cooperation shown by Mr Abbattista during
the investigations was unexceptional and, to the extent set out in this Notice, it
does not accept the explanations he provided. Accordingly, the cooperation he
provided should neither increase nor decrease the financial penalty to be imposed.
The Authority notes the lack of previous regulatory disciplinary findings against Mr
Abbattista but does not consider this merits a reduction in penalty. As noted at
paragraph 21 above, the Authority does not consider it necessary for there to have
been Authority guidance or case law addressing the particular technique used by
Mr Abbattista for him to have understood that it was not permissible to place orders
without intending to fulfil them.
45.
The Authority notes the effect of the investigation on Mr Abbattista and his family
but it does not justify a reduction in the financial penalty.
Procedural unfairness
46.
Mr Abbattista has suffered a considerable procedural unfairness in not having been
invited to attend a further interview with the Authority at a later stage in the
investigation. Had he been, he would have been able to address the Authority
directly in relation to its flawed case theory. It is not enough to say that Mr
Abbattista can be confident of a fair hearing before the RDC. In the interests of
natural justice, the Authority ought to have sought input from him on the central
issue of his purpose in placing the trial orders before issuing a Warning Notice. Its
failure to do so has led to his incurring defence costs unnecessarily, as well as
causing distress to him and his family. Certain information relied on was not shown
to him prior to either of his interviews and some has come to light only very
recently. These are matters that ought to be taken into account in addition to the
mitigating factors set out above.
47.
The Authority’s decision-maker in this case, the RDC (see paragraph 8.3 of this
Notice), has reached the decision set out in this Notice after careful consideration
of all the evidence available to it, including Mr Abbattista’s representations. Mr
Abbattista has been provided with all the information seen by the RDC and has had
the opportunity to comment on all that information. The Authority does not
consider that Mr Abbattista’s complaint about the lack of a further interview
undermines the evidence relied upon by it in reaching its decision. Any complaints
about the conduct of the Authority may be pursued by Mr Abbattista using the
Complaints Scheme established under the Financial Services Act 2012.